How state ownership came to China

Transitional periods in history are always interesting to me, but they are usually under-researched. It’s easier to find books about how one era or system worked in its heyday then works that discuss the shift from one to another. I’ve always wanted to know more about China’s transition from the chaotic civil war period to the orthodox planned economy of the 1950s, and I’m finding Andrew Walder’s new book China Under Mao: A Revolution Derailed to be a very clearly written analytical history of this period. In line with my interest in all things SOE, the following excerpt is from chapter 4:

From the late 1920s, the Communist Party’s strategy for revolution focused on rural China. Mao’s early doctrine about class struggle was applied in regions that the party controlled, and as the PLA rolled south and west in its military conquest of China after 1947, CCP cadres orchestrated revolution in villages according to a well-practiced script. The cities, however, were another matter entirely. Not until April 1946 did the party take control of a major city, when they took over Harbin from departing Soviet forces. … Initially, their strategy was to implement military control and leave existing ownership of industry and commerce intact, with the exception of state enterprises controlled by the Nationalists. In the cities, the main emphasis was to stabilize the economy and promote industrial development, not to obliterate the economic foundations of the old society.  …

The urban private sector declined immediately after 1949, even before the party leadership announced its decision to move toward socialism in 1953. Government agencies began to take over banks and wholesale suppliers, making it more difficult for businesses to obtain credit and financing, supplies, and customers. These changes deprived the private sector of the means to compete and grow. … Increasingly, private firms depended on state contracts for their business: the output sold by private firms on state contracts rose from 12 to 56 percent during the same period. … Without any explicit attacks on the private sector, it was gradually being squeezed by state policy and made dependent on state agencies.

The gradual squeezing of the private sector turned into a frontal attack in 1952. The party launched the Three-Anti movement to combat “corruption, waste, and bureaucratism,” and the abuse of power by cadres in urban administrations. The campaign struck civil servants who had stayed in their posts and pledged loyalty to the new regime. … The campaign then pivoted to an attack on private businesses. The Three Anti campaign was merged into a Three Anti, Five Anti campaign. The new claim was that corruption among cadres was caused by the business practices of private entrepreneurs. The new Five Anti targeted “tax evasion, bribery, cheating on government contracts, theft of economic intelligence, and stealing state assets.” Work teams moved into private businesses, demanded to see their accounts, and conducted all-night interrogations that pressured business owners to confess to corruption and tax evasion, reveal the source of their “illegal profits,” and divulge hidden assets. Large fines were levied that bankrupted many businesses, which subsequently closed. Many business owners “voluntarily” turned their firms over to the government as payment for their alleged back taxes and criminal fines.

And there’s lots more of interest on other aspects of the creation of the planned economy. Inspired by this reading, I dug up some historical statistics and pulled together the following chart to illustrate the progress of nationalization (the figures in this chart are slightly different from the ones Walder cites in his text, as I’m using a later statistical compilation with revised data). It’s interesting to note that pre-revolutionary China already had a significant amount of state-owned enterprises, as the Nationalists had no aversion to state ownership and made some attempts at planning industrial development (Rana Mitter’s excellent history of the civil war period Forgotten Ally discusses this theme).

abolition of private ownership in 1950s

Further reading: a more detailed account of the early transition to state ownership that Walder cites is Bennis Wai-yip So, “The Policy-Making and Political Economy of the Abolition of Private Ownership in the Early 1950s: Findings from New Material,” a 2002 article in The China Quarterly (JSTOR link).

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out /  Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out /  Change )

Connecting to %s

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.