Eileen Chang on China

Eileen Chang’s first book of essays, Written on Water, in the marvelous Andrew F. Jones translation, has been recently reprinted, and I’ve been savoring it in small pieces. Published when Chang was just 24 years old, the book shows her as something like the Joan Didion of pre-revolutionary China: a preternaturally sharp and cool observer. The discursive, personal essays are not easy to summarize or excerpt, and are short enough that you should just read them. But she made a few offhand generalizations about her country that still rang true to me, 80 years after their first publication, and which can stand on their own.

This one is from “What Is Essential Is That Names Be Right”:

China is a nation of words. When an emperor met with misfortune, he would immediately change the name of the reign period in hopes of turning the country’s luck in the year to come. What used to be the Twelfth Year of the Martial Advent would suddenly become the Inaugural Year of the Era of Great Celebration, thus putting an immediate end to the sufferings of the past. An excessive faith in the power of words is our most distinctive characteristic.

This one is from “Peking Opera Through Foreign Eyes”:

Chinese people like the law, and they like breaking the law, too, not necessarily through murder or plunder of property but by way of trivial and unmotivated violations of the rules. If a wooden sign by the side of the road reads, “Stay to the Right,” they will inevitably walk on the left. …such a spirit [is] less a subversion of the system itself than a playful tug at an object reverenced by all, a tug that ultimately becomes a form of recognition rather than rebellion.

This one is from “Poetry And Nonsense”:

Living in China has something lovable about it: amid dirt and chaos and grief, one discovers everywhere precious things, things that bring joy for an afternoon, a day, a lifetime. I hear the roads in Germany are so squeaky clean that you can use them as a mirror, that they are wide, ruler straight, tidy to a fault, and planted all along their length with towering trees. And yet I suspect that walking along such a road day after day would drive one mad.

Then there is Canada, a country that in the majority of people’s minds seems to lack any distinguishing characteristics whatsoever: a formless and desolate land. And yet my aunt says it is the best place in the world, with a cool climate, blue skies, emerald-colored grass, creamy white Western-style houses with red roofs as far as one can see, each with a freshly scrubbed look and boasting its own garden. If she could choose, she would live the rest of her life there. If I were to choose, I could not bear to leave China: I’m homesick even before I leave home.

Chang, of course, did leave China, and spent the last 40 years of her life in the US.

China’s moment of flux: a podcast with Jude Blanchette

In mid-December, I recorded a podcast with Jude Blanchette of the Center for Strategic and International Studies, which has now been published, on their website and via the usual podcast channels. Jude’s one of the best informed and most insightful observers of Chinese politics that I know, and we covered a lot of interesting territory. With the kind permission of CSIS, I’ve produced the following transcript of our conversation, which has been lightly edited for clarity.

Jude: China has emerged as one of the 21st century’s most consequential nations, making it more important than ever to understand how the country is governed. Welcome to Pekingology, the podcast that unpacks China’s evolving political system. I’m Jude Blanchette, the Freeman Chair of China Studies at CSIS, and this week I’m joined by Andrew Batson, China Research Director at Gavekal Dragonomics. Today we’ll be discussing his blog post, Xi’s New Growth Synthesis. Andrew, thanks for joining us.

Andrew: Thanks for having me, Jude.

Jude: So I wanted to start by asking how you first became interested in China and as a related question, how did you find your way to this career of thinking and writing about China’s political economy?

Andrew: My career pathway is a bit weird. The way I got into being a China expert, I think, is different from a lot of other people that I know who do similar things. A lot of the people that I’ve met over the years who do the kind of thing that I do, they got into China-related careers because they had some kind of early life experience that pushed them in that direction. They studied Chinese in high school, maybe, or they have a family connection to China that made it natural to be curious about China.

Actually, I don’t have any of those things. I’m a white kid. I grew up in a small town in southeastern Louisiana. My exposure to China growing up was that my dad would take us out to a Chinese restaurant on Friday nights. That’s kind of it. I basically became interested in China because I lived in China, not the other way around.

And that happened through a pretty circuitous chain of events. But basically, when I was trying to break into journalism and get a job, I went around to meet people, and I was introduced to some people who were involved in journalism in Asia. They introduced me to some people, and they introduced me to some people, and I ended up getting connected with this consulting company in Beijing of all places. The consulting company was looking for educated young people that they could underpay and exploit. So, you know, naturally I was interested in that.

At the time I hadn’t really ever given much thought to China particularly, but here was someone who was willing to pay me to go live in a foreign country and that seemed like a pretty interesting chance that I shouldn’t say no to. So I said, sure, I’ll give it a shot. And then I showed up in Beijing and basically started from scratch. I didn’t have any knowledge of Chinese when I first moved here. I didn’t have that much background knowledge, didn’t have many preconceptions. And because of that, I was immediately confronted with this huge puzzle, right? I’d placed myself in this completely different physical, cultural, social environment. And I had to figure out how it worked. In a sense, that’s what I’ve been doing ever since.

I think the other piece of my biography that’s maybe relevant to this and has shaped my approach is that, although my job for a long time now has been to analyze the Chinese economy, I actually wasn’t trained as an economist. I was trained as an anthropologist: at school, my undergraduate degree was in anthropology. We had a very rigorous exposure, I would say, to a kind of more traditional mid-century style of social science, a little bit different than what people get taught today in most places. The organizing questions that we were asked to investigate were, how do human social systems function, and how do we understand the diversity of human social systems: what are the differences, what do those differences mean?

And I think if I look back at the stuff I’ve been doing over the years, basically the question I’ve been trying to answer, from different angles and in different ways, is what is the nature of China’s system? How is its system different from other systems? And I think the reason I asked the question in that way is because I was exposed to this particular school of social science at a formative age.

Jude: Andrew, one of the things I wanted to ask you, and actually I’m going to make this a new feature on the podcast. I always appreciate sections of podcasts where they ask for book recommendations, but I usually find that that entails me having to go spend $30 on a book. And then realistically, I’m probably not going to read the book. It’s going to end up in the pile here, as you can see my behind me.

But I’ve often found sometimes the most helpful tool for me is when someone says something, some sort of framework or heuristic or insight that actually is an “a ha” moment and is a tool that I can then use to bring to bear on thinking about China. So as I wrote to you in an email, I wanted to use you as a guinea pig for a new running feature of the podcast, which is, is there some, borrowing from Daniel Dennett, an intuition pump or a heuristic or some insight that you have heard or developed that helps you think through China?

And just for the audience, I’m not sure this is a heuristic as such, but just to give an example, you often hear some people say China’s not a monolith. Now that’s a really simple comment, but I think people who articulate that, what they’re trying to do is to get to a deeper insight where they want folks to embrace the complexity of the Chinese system, rather than thinking of it as Xi Jinping in the mothership, turning dials to get the system to operate as he wants.

You think a lot about thinking about China. So I wonder if I could put the question to you. Is there some sort of, again, a heuristic, an intuition pump, an insight, a framework that you find very useful and might be useful to others.

Andrew: Yeah, I thought quite a bit about this. It’s a tricky question. So I came up with something, I’m not sure it’s going to be an “a ha” moment for you, but maybe it’ll be helpful for other people. Because this is something that’s come up in a lot of conversations I’ve had about China. One basic, simple thing about China, that I keep coming back to, is that it’s really important to realize that Chinese people mostly believe that China is a great nation that should be at the forefront of the world.

So what I mean by this is not that the Chinese people are all these rabid, frothing-at-the-mouth nationalists. That’s not at all my point. What I mean is more that there’s a baseline assumption across all kinds of people that you meet, of different classes, of different political beliefs, that essentially there’s no particular reason why China should not be the best in the world, at any given thing, regardless of what that thing is. And if China isn’t the best in the world, then it can be, and they just have to work harder to get there.

When I was living in China, I encountered this attitude a lot, so it didn’t seem exceptional to me or that remarkable. It was just part of the background, it was there all the time. As I’ve spent more time in other developing countries, and more time in developed countries as well, I’ve really started to appreciate that this attitude is kind of unusual. There’s a lot of small countries or poor countries, where the people are in fact not really confident that they can be the best in the world at any particular thing. They’re very conscious that they lag behind other countries in the world, that their position is relatively poor and it doesn’t seem necessarily plausible to them that that’s going to fundamentally change.

And that belief might not be wrong. So, if we’re talking about Spain or Indonesia, just to pick some country names out of a hat, is it really realistic for those countries to have aspirations to be, for example, the global center for artificial intelligence research? Might not be. But it is kind of realistic for China to have those aspirations.

The other thing I would say about this is, again, it’s an attitude. It’s not a political belief or a political creed. So a lot of Chinese people have this attitude, but it’s compatible with a lot of different political beliefs. It doesn’t determine, necessarily, where China ends up.

I think if you talk to Chinese people who are more on the right of the political spectrum, in Chinese domestic terms, they may tend to think that the way that China becomes the best in the world, an even better place, is by converging with the global ideals, whether this be the rule of law, market economics, individual freedom, and so on. And for Chinese people who are more on the left of the political spectrum, again, in the domestic context, they may tend to think more it’s about China following its own path and using the power of the socialist state to shape outcomes. So how China gets to be the best in the world is something that Chinese people are debating amongst themselves.

But I think they all share the premise that China is going to keep becoming a better place, that it is a great nation, and is going to become an even greater nation in the future. So I think if you wanted to offend every Chinese person across the entire political spectrum, what you would do is to deny that premise or try to throw roadblocks in its way.

Jude: Before we get to your blog posts, let me ask you one additional high elevation question. I read your professional, day-job writing and I also read your blog posts and I like both, but what I especially like about the blog is I can see that you’re still puzzling through, trying to understand the Chinese political system. You draw on comparative writings, you sort of puzzle through government documents or party documents that come out, and we’re going to talk about one of these posts in a minute.

But I wanted to, before we get into that, ask you: We’re at a time where I think a lot of people see massive change occurring in China in its growth model and its political system. I’m curious, as you draw on your experience, in China and analyzing China, and as we record this, you’re in Beijing right now, when you think about China’s political system or political economy, are there beliefs you had, which you now just fundamentally question? Are there beliefs you’ve long held, which still hold constant when you think about the structure of China’s political system and its economy?

In other words, what do you think you know about China? In a deep, true sense. And what are the areas of your knowledge about China where the theses are tentative or shifting?

Andrew: Thank you for putting the question in that way, because it is true that I’m still a student of this stuff and will continue to be a student, you know, probably for the rest of my life. It’s a process to figure this stuff out. I think one thing that’s changed for me over the last 10 years is that I feel like I do have a better understanding of the Chinese political system than I did before. I’ve done a lot more reading about that, and also just had more time to observe how things work and talk to people.

So at the moment, I have reasonably high confidence that I understand the basic parameters of the Chinese system. The key concept for me is basically the idea that China is a Leninist system. And this is a technical term, not a term of abuse. I learned this from reading, in particular, Joseph Fewsmith, who’s a well-known scholar of Chinese politics, and also this guy Ken Jowitt, who’s an older scholar of the Soviet Union.

A Leninist system is fundamentally a hierarchical, top-down political system in which the cadres, the members of the Communist Party, are mobilized to pursue political goals. This mobilization is a key idea, and the political goals are a key idea. And the reason these are important is because China is not actually governed by a neutral civil service or a bureaucracy that’s based on following written rules of procedure and implementing regulations in a value-neutral way. If we look at China, we see something that appears on its surface to resemble such a bureaucracy, but actually that bureaucracy is subordinate to the Leninist political system, or to put it a different way, the Leninist political system interpenetrates the bureaucracy at every level. So that’s on the political side.

And then on the economic side, I’ve also spent a lot of time trying to figure out what exactly is the nature of China’s system. The term that I come back to, which is maybe not ideal, but seems to be the best that we have available, in English anyway, is state capitalism. And so this is what I use. This is just a shorthand term an economy in which there are high levels of government ownership, high levels of government intervention, but these coexist with market mechanisms, the decentralized setting of prices and so on.

I think in China’s case, this kind of political system and this kind of economic system reinforce each other. They’re highly compatible for obviously for historical reasons, but also in a logical way, right? The key dynamic of a Leninist system is that the leaders, they do not just feel that they are entitled to direct the development of their nation in a particular way, but they’re actually obligated to. That’s their job. This is the reason the government has power.

The government’s role is not to use its power to provide a neutral framework in which individual people and companies and different entities can all pursue their own goals and aspirations. This is what I take to be the defining conceit of Western liberalism: life, liberty, and the pursuit of happiness. The government’s job is just to enable all this.

In a Leninist system, that’s not the government’s job. The job is to push the whole society to go in a certain direction. And so if that’s the underlying political conception, it’s actually difficult to have a fully market-based economy because the government, the state, the party is not inclined to just accept the market outcomes. They’re inclined to mobilize the society to achieve certain goals and use the different tools they have available. And that’s part of what these state-owned enterprises and different regulatory interventions are for.

And in the other direction, right, the fact that you have this whole cavalcade of state owned enterprises and different government institutions to organize and direct different parts of society justifies or encourages a Leninist approach. Because otherwise, you know, what is this stuff for? Why do we have all this state ownership? Why do we have all this state intervention? It must be for some reason. If there’s no reason to use it, we could just get rid of it. And so since they don’t want to get rid of it, they find reasons to use it.

Basically, my intellectual process of the last 10 years has been specifically to try to figure out what’s the reason for all the weird things about China’s economy that people obsess about. Why do we have such high rates of investment? Why are there these boom and bust cycles? Why is China able to have high rates of economic growth, even though it doesn’t have very good legal institutions? All these kinds of puzzles. In my view, basically it all comes back to this basic political structure, this basic political economy of a Leninist system.

So that’s the thing I feel reasonably certain about. For now.

Jude: I don’t know if you’ve ever read Michael Oakeshott, the London School of Economics political philosopher whose heyday was in the fifties and sixties, but I’ve often thought about him because he talked about two different conceptions of statehood. One is what he called a democracy, which is, as you just described, a political system that is not ends oriented, but is an institutional set up with laws and apolitical bureaucrats.

And then he talks about, contrasts that, with this conception of teleocracy, obviously coming from the Greek word telios meaning, moving towards an end. And he’s writing this in a description of the Soviet union, but I’ve always liked his work on teleocracy because I think it jives with what you were just saying about China as a system oriented towards objectives or goals. To put it in a more crude way, I thought about the party as something like a shark: sharks die if they stop moving forward.

In a fundamental sense, the Chinese system isn’t structured absent some conception of a goal to be striving for. You couldn’t run it. Cadres wouldn’t know what to do. If. It didn’t have that sort of continual churn of plans and objectives and meta objectives, whether these are high level Marxist aspirations or just five-year plans. So it is a unique feature of these Leninist systems, which I appreciate you highlighting because I do think it’s important.

Let me grab the steering wheel and turn the direction suddenly, if I may, which is I wanted to now start getting into some of the substance of what you’ve been thinking and writing about both in your blog post on Xi’s new growth synthesis, but also some of the other thinking and writing you’ve been doing about the growth of securitization in the policy agenda in China.

And I thought I might start with something which I don’t have a clear answer to and think you might take a better stab at it. Which is, before we talk about securitization or the growth of securitization, I think there’s confusion that I hear about how external analysts and observers think about growth and political stability. I often hear people, indeed, just in the past few weeks, I’ve heard various people say, that on the one hand, Xi Jinping doesn’t care about growth. He’s willing to supplement growth for higher objectives, whether these be Taiwan, or to build a fortress economy that can withstand what he sees as a containment/suppression/encirclement strategy by the United States.

Then I’ll hear people say, well if growth falls below 3%, then the Communist Party is doomed. So they have to find ways to revive the economy. And you’re probably old enough to remember this too, I think this is back in the mid to late 2000s, I just remember there was always this thing in news articles where it would say if Chinese growth drops below 8%, I don’t know why 8% or how we got there, but if it drops below 8%, you’re going to see massive instability in the system.

So how do you, at a higher level, think about trade-offs, or the connection between economic activity and growth, and political stability in the Chinese context. Not in the context of Norway or the United States, where I think the relationship is different. Do you buy the logic that whatever the number is, whether it’s 8%, 3% or 1%, there is an absolute floor underneath which, if growth craters, it will have a demonstrative rippling effect of instability. Do you think this is not the right way we should think about how they think about the growth-stability relationship? Or is my question so inchoate that you have a better way that I could frame this?

Andrew: So the answer to most of your questions is no. I don’t think there’s a floor to growth where it triggers instability.

I remember very well this debate over 8% growth and social stability from back in the 2000s. This was one of my formative experiences as a China analyst, trying to understand and intervene in this debate, so actually, I have a pretty detailed memory of this. My recollection is when that came up back in the day, it was because somebody had done a calculation, I think it might have been the World Bank, and they basically said: If you look at the number of new jobs that are created every year, and then you divide that by the GDP growth rate, this shows that each point of GDP growth generates X number of jobs. Therefore, this implies that you need a certain amount of GDP growth to have enough jobs, because based on the population, or number of college graduates, you’re going to need this number of jobs. And therefore you have to have this number of GDP growth to deliver that.

So as economic analysis, obviously this is totally nonsense. Or maybe it wasn’t obvious, because a lot of people said it. But I mean, it’s total nonsense. There’s no such thing as a fixed relationship between GDP growth and job creation in any economy anywhere. And anyway, I think the calculations in the Chinese case didn’t make that much sense because government actually doesn’t have very good data on job creation. So the numbers that they were plugging into that equation were probably bogus in the first place. Still, I think this kind of argument got traction inside of China and outside of China, but I think for somewhat different reasons.

Inside China, the reason it got traction and the reason people found it attractive is because there’s a group of people in China who wanted the government to focus on employment rather than GDP growth, right? They saw the pursuit of GDP growth as creating all kinds of distortions and problems. And fundamentally what really matters for people’s lives, for prosperity, is job creation. So we should really think about GDP growth as a means of creating jobs rather than as this abstract target we’re trying to hit for no particular reason.

And that idea, I think, has been quite influential in China. When Li Keqiang, the late lamented, was premier, he often said that employment was the most important thing. So at the level of rhetoric, that seems to be influential. But I think, if you actually look at how he or how other administrations actually ran the economy, it was pretty obvious that the labor market was not what was driving how they managed the economy or what key decisions were being made. It was usually other kinds of cyclical indicators of the economy, the property market or industry or what have you. And I think to be honest, they probably don’t really have enough accurate information about the labor market to use it as a guide to short-term macro policy.

Outside of China, I think the reason people latched on to this idea was because it played to certain prejudices or preconceptions about the nature of China’s political system. I think there’s a tendency for people, in the U. S. particularly, to think that with the Chinese people living under an authoritarian regime, they must inherently always be dissatisfied with the regime, and they must always be looking for ways to overthrow it. If they’re not being constantly pacified with lots of money, they would just rise up the instant that happened.

As with many things, there is a grain of truth to this. So if we look comparatively across different countries, different forms of government, you can correct me on this, but I think the finding is that authoritarian regimes tend to be a little more fragile and have less popular legitimacy than other kinds of political systems. So there’s more of an issue for them. But I think we both know that it’s just not true that daily life in China is some kind of dystopian hellscape that is going to force people to rise up in a revolt if the economy is not so good.

I think the other idea about political system that’s been very influential outside China is this idea that there’s a social contract, right? That people in China traded, in a more or less explicit way, political freedom for economic growth. We’ll accept not having all of these political freedoms as long as enough prosperity is delivered to compensate us for this loss.

There is some truth to this. I think economic performance is one of the ways in which the government shows people that it’s doing a good job, that it deserves their support. But obviously, or again maybe not so obviously, it’s not true that people’s satisfaction with the government is mechanically related to the GDP numbers or mechanically related to economic performance in such a specific way.

So yeah, I don’t think that there is any particular fixed relationship between political stability, in the sense of at least of popular unrest, and economic growth, that there’s some kind of trigger that we can identify where economic problems become serious enough that that’s going to have an impact on the foundations of the political system.

Jude: Let me ask you another related question, and this is very much a live topic of discussion now, which is how economic growth is being rebalanced in relation to another goal, which is security or national security. You’ve written on this, there’s stuff on your blog on this, so I might ask you to regurgitate what you’ve already said on this.

This is a really interesting question for me. Part of it is a little bit of Freudian psychology, of people trying to get in Xi Jinping’s head. I will hear people say, Xi Jinping doesn’t care about growth. I don’t agree with that statement, but I understand, as you were just saying, there’s a kernel of truth there.

We’re seeing security rise to the fore of the active policy agenda in ways that are clearly at an elevated pitch from previous leadership groups. But I wanted to get your thoughts on this. If someone says to you, growth is out the window and it’s all about security, what’s your response? If someone says they’re trying to balance growth and security, what’s your response?

How do you think through what, on the surface, to some extent appear to be zero-sum trade offs. What’s your thesis for what the Chinese are trying to do and how these two objectives sit together or separate?

Andrew: So the way I think about this goes back to this concept of the Leninist system that’s organized around a mobilizational goal for the whole society.

For me, I think the fundamental way to understand what Xi Jinping is doing, particularly since his second term, is that he is changing the mobilizational goal. And that the mobilizational goal had been basically the same from 1978 until 2017, when Xi gave his speech at the Party Congress. In that speech, he basically said, in so many words, that there had been one goal in the reform era, which was the pursuit of economic growth, or development, or prosperity, there are different synonyms for this, and that that was over. And that now China is on a different trajectory.

I think where I would differ slightly from the way that you phrased the question is that I don’t think that he’s clearly articulated what the new trajectory is. So I think security is part of this new message, but it hasn’t been made that clear. What was very clear, and continues to be very clear, is that the pursuit of economic growth has been downgraded in importance relative to other goals. It’s not gone. It’s not that they don’t care about growth, but the system was previously organized around the pursuit of economic growth, and now it is not.

What is the system organized around now? Well, I would say it’s not that clear, to be perfectly honest, and this is why I think that, in a way, that there’s a lot of political instability in China. And this goes back to your previous question, where you’re asking about political stability in the Chinese context.

So I think if you think in terms of China having a Leninist political system, where what’s fundamentally important is having the mobilizational goal and then communicating that mobilizational goal, in that context, actually, China’s in a moment, I would say, of political instability, because the new mobilizational goal has not been clearly communicated. There’s some directional guidance, but the actual goal is not that clear.

When I say that there’s political instability, I don’t mean that there’s different factions within the Communist Party or that there’s going to be riots in the street or a coup or anything like that. Xi has very tight political control. He has left very little room for any competing power centers to emerge. But I think there’s instability in the system’s own terms. There’s just ambiguity about what the mobilizational goal is. There’s ambiguity about what people should be doing.

Xi has talked about different things. One of the organizing conceptions in his original speech in 2017 was this idea of a “better life.” That’s about as vague as you can possibly get, right? It has all kinds of different components. So, we shouldn’t pursue economic growth, we should pursue a better life instead. What does that mean in practice? I think nobody knows.

More recently, there’s been a lot of emphasis on national security, and technological self sufficiency. These are very specific goals, but are they enough to function as like the overall goal for the whole system?

I think the problem here is that this talk about national security and self-sufficiency, the only thing that really makes those make sense, and seem convincing to people, is the fact that there are worries about China getting into a conflict with the U.S. The U. S. has put tariffs and technological sanctions on China. And China clearly has to have a response to this. I think that’s why this talk about technological self sufficiency has gotten a lot of traction and is quite popular in China.

But I think it would be quite a difficult thing for Xi to come out and say explicitly that the goal for the nation is to prepare for a war with the U.S. Because that’s not a goal that people are really going to get behind. War is bad. People don’t like it. They’re not going to go to war if they don’t have to. So I think the problem with security as a mobilizational goal is that it’s not an attractive one, fundamentally.

You can frame the security, self-sufficiency issues more as, oh, we need to do things to protect ourselves and it’s all just in case. But I think that doesn’t really function as an organizing principle for the whole society. So I think what you’ve ended up with is this confusing signaling, where the government is saying, well, we shouldn’t pursue economic growth as aggressively as we did in the past. And we should pursue some of these other things, technological self sufficiency, food security, the preservation of traditional culture, there’s a long list, more aggressively than in the past.

But again, that’s not that satisfying. And it doesn’t, fundamentally, give the actors in the system very clear guidance about what their priorities should be, and how they should make particular decisions. Ultimately, this is my diagnosis about why everyone in China seems so unsettled and seems really uncertain right now. They literally don’t know where the country is going.

I don’t mean that in an abstract sense. It’s in the sense of, the country is organized around having a goal towards which it should be proceeding. And people aren’t really sure what that goal is. The Leninist system is unsettled and therefore the people who live in this system are also unsettled.

Jude: You had a really good blog post on what must be the level of relative confusion or uncertainty for cadres in the system who are clearly being transitioned to a new paradigm, but without, as you say laser-like clarity on on precisely what’s the relative weighting of the various objectives. This does exist at some level in terms of performance indicators that cadres are evaluated on, but it’s clear from just anecdotal evidence that those are not sufficient to give actors in the system certainty of action, knowing that here’s the green zone, here’s the yellow, here’s the red. And, of course, they still live in a world where there are growth targets and growth expectations. If you’re in Guizhou, you probably also have some expectations. You’re going to develop some sort of innovation cluster, but you’re also going to have some national security imperative. So it does seem like Xi Jinping is pushing the system into a new level of dysfunctionality.

Let me now ask you to pick up your rusty, dirty crystal ball, brush it off, and see if you can peer into it. I know no one likes to predict the future, especially on China, and I know you’re a careful, nuanced thinker, so the answer, I will say it for you, on the questions I’m about to ask you is probably, I don’t know.

But nonetheless, I wanted to get your sense of, you’ve laid out a picture just now of an inchoate, somewhat confused policy agenda that is sending multiple signals. You probably have actors in the system interpreting those signals differently. You have China dealing with a very different external environment. You know, it had a very benign external environment from the late 1990s through till fairly recently. You have a political system that is becoming more, in some sense, more capital-L Leninist, but also in some ways de-Leninized as Xi Jinping really personalizes the system.

So first question is, how strong, how robust and resilient do you think this political-economic system is to withstand internal challenges from Xi Jinping trying to move the system or shift gears, and externally, whether it’s Chinese corporates now facing a much harder regulatory environment, BRI facing pushback. You pick the policy initiative and there are challenges. I don’t think anyone anymore is in the China galactic ascendancy trajectory. Are you China muddles through? Are you China can get its mojo back? Or are you China not on the cliff, but heading in the direction of a more catastrophic hard landing that could be a political hard landing? Or option D, which is whatever you, whichever option I didn’t list that you think is better.

Andrew: I think there are a lot of issues in the Chinese economy and political system they’re trying to deal with. We outlined why it’s been pretty challenging to deal with them. I would say that in the medium term, my bias is to not be completely pessimistic, and this kind of goes back to what I was talking about at the opening of our conversation, where I feel like there’s this general sense among Chinese people that China’s going to get better, and if they work hard, they can achieve it.

Again, I would be frank that this is sort of more of an intuitive sense than something I can justify very rigorously with lots of evidence and statistics. But I do feel like there is a continued momentum in China for it to catch up with the technology and capabilities of other countries, and that catch up can continue to propel China’s incomes up over time.

But I feel that this is more of a bottom-up process, right? That it’s not something that’s necessarily driven by all of these government initiatives, in terms of industrial policy, R&D subsidies, what have you. And to some extent, this bottom-up dynamism in China exists despite these government policies or even in opposition to them. I think it’s still very much a real thing, so we should not assume that it has gone completely away.

And I guess the other thing I would say this just in terms of global perspective, of global impact is that it’s hard to imagine a future scenario in which China becomes internationally irrelevant. So maybe China becomes more relevant in a good way, maybe becomes more relevant in a bad way, but it’s very unlikely for it to be less relevant.

The shape of the world economy has changed very substantially and China has huge stocks of manufacturing capacity, of technological capability, that are not going to go away, even if the economic outcomes are poor. Economists like to talk about stocks and flow. So maybe the flow of new economic activity, i.e. growth, is weak over the next few years, but China’s already built up a lot. It’s 20 to 30% of world manufacturing output. That’s not going to go away.

So I think we should broadly anticipate that even if China faces a lot of challenges, it’s going to continue to be relevant in a macro sense, and also in several very specific senses. It seems pretty obvious that China is very far along the way to becoming the global center of production for clean energy technology that the rest of the world is going to use in the transition away from fossil fuels. So that’s almost a done deal.

To go back to your question of more generally, how does China deal with these problems? I think in my day job, the problem that we’ve been trying to figure out is basically what kind of economic policy decisions does China make given its set of priorities and the fact that the priorities now are clearly different than they were in the past? I think over the past 12 months in China, since basically the Covid restrictions were dropped, there’s been a lot of flux, a lot of change. And I think there’s this ongoing process of everyone within the system trying to get more clarity on what the overall goal is. Officials in the government, and also people in the population at large, they’re trying to decode the signals. And also the people at the top, Xi Jinping and his associates, are at the same time trying to fine tune the signals in order to get the results that they desire.

So you’ve seen Xi come up with various new formulations that try to synthesize what you talked about as the growth and security concerns, or new formulations that imply that growth and security are not opposed to one another. That it’s not a zero sum game: we can do both at the same time and everything will be great.

In fact, it’s a very interesting and uncertain moment for Chinese policymaking. I think there’s a general sense that all of the economic problems over the past year have pushed the government to make some tough choices to face up more explicitly to these trade-offs, and to try to come up with a more coherent policy agenda.

So where does this balance between growth and the rest of the agenda, like security concerns, where do they stand now? Obviously, economic growth is pretty poor right now, the property market is in real trouble. And you’re seeing, at the margin, a little bit more of a pivot back towards growth-supporting policies. That’s what a lot of the economic analysis and discussion domestically is about right now: oh, we’re getting these positive signals finally, so things are good.

But I think what the government is trying to do is to find a new synthesis, right? They want to find a way to have decent economic growth, a way to stabilize the current situation, that’s compatible with this new political agenda, that doesn’t involve just giving up and saying, oh, we were wrong to try to pursue this new set of goals. We can actually still pursue this new set of goals and also get these good things.

I think a lot of people domestically want to see the old system come back. They want to see the old growth goal come back. They want China to pivot away from the pursuit of security, a better life, this different political agenda that Xi has outlined, and back towards, let’s just do economic growth and not worry about the other stuff.

If you look back over this past year, you see every marginally positive development in the economy has been interpreted as showing that this has happened. So first: oh, they dropped Covid controls, that means they don’t care about this other stuff and it’s all out. And, no. So then at the beginning of this year, the new premier Li Qiang made all these nice comments about the private sector when he was appointed. People were like, ah, see with this new administration, we’re back to the good old days. Uh, no. Then we had the Politburo meeting saying, we need to do more to support growth. And people said, oh, look, finally, they’ve seen the light and it’s going to be off to the races again. It wasn’t. The most recent one, Xi Jinping went to Shanghai and people said, oh, look, this is a signal there’s now more focus on economic growth. I think basically all of these interpretations have been wrong and people will probably continue to make this kind of interpretation in the future. And it’s still going to be wrong in the future. That’s my prediction.

I think the old system where you had this decentralized pursuit of high growth, and you tolerate anything as long as it gets growth–this is gone. Xi has killed it. He’s not going to bring it back. But at the same time, I think it’s true that they haven’t figured out what is the exact balance they want between growth and these other concerns. Between growth and security is the way you put it. It’s being renegotiated. It’s in flux.

And so that’s why I think right now it’s a super interesting moment for Chinese economic policy. This is what I look at every day. There’s huge political pressure, and there’s huge economic pressure. The economic problems are very serious, and the political constraints are also very binding. So they need to come up with some new ideas. They need to find some ways to help the economy that are going to be consistent with these new political priorities. They have to get growth, but they have to get growth in a way that’s compatible with this objective of, we need to restructure the economy to help us prevail in the global competition with the U. S.

So I think it’s a very interesting moment. It’s a very uncertain moment. Almost certainly, China is going to come up with some new things to surprise us as a result of these intense pressures. It’s not guaranteed that the balance they find is going to be the perfect one, or that it’s going to generate the kind of growth outcomes that people want or expect. It is a moment of flux and change, I would say, in the Chinese system. Maybe that’s a cop out.

Jude: It’s the truth, so it may be a cop out, but I also don’t know a better answer.

And anyone selling certainty in this moment is going to have a bridge they’re going to sell you next as well. So find the folks more credible when they’re willing to frame it, just as you did. You’re in Beijing right now, so you’d have a better sense, but I do pick up from Chinese friends and interlocutors that same sense of unease. Where problems China had to be sure, but there was some certainty in the trajectory, namely, tomorrow is going to be better than today. Your kid’s life was going to be better than yours, but even with your own lifetime, you are going to have likely ample opportunities for improvement. And that window feels to be collapsing. And I can absolutely see the desire of many to get back to the old growth model. Again, with all the pathologies and problems it had, it also had a lot to offer.

We’re definitely in new territory. But again, I am just so glad Andrew, that you’re thinking and writing about this. I would like to say that all audience members should go shake their couch cushions and find some money to become clients of Gavekal Dragonomics, I realize that’s probably unrealistic for most. So luckily, Andrew, you are writing. frequently, and I think with great nuance about a lot of these challenges on your blog, The Tangled Woof. If people are thinking, what the hell does The Tangled Woof mean? You’ll have to go to andrewbatson.com, there is an explanation of what that means. But I can’t recommend your analysis enough, Andrew, and really look forward to reading what you write next.

So thank you for your insights. Thanks for your writing and thanks for your time today.

Andrew: Thanks so much, Jude. It was a really great conversation.

The education of Li Keqiang

Even in death, China’s former premier Li Keqiang cannot escape the shadow of his overweening boss, Xi Jinping. The commentary around his untimely passing–Li was only 68 and not obviously in poor health–has been filled with implicit and explicit comparisons to the man he served loyally for a decade as China’s second-ranked Communist Party leader.

The general temptation to see Li as representing an alternative school of thought and the potential for a different political trajectory is as strong as it is unsupported by real evidence. Despite much speculation about internal differences between Xi and Li, the system is designed to prevent us from knowing much about the personal views and predilections of Chinese politicians.

The differences in their background made it almost inevitable that Xi and Li would be perceived as representing different ideas, interest groups and, dare I say, classes. Education everywhere is a strong determinant of social position, and due to the accidents of Chinese history, the educational experiences of the two men differed dramatically.

Li was among the first group of students to take the restored college entrance examination in 1977, in which he did well enough to earn a place at the prestigious Peking University. That made him a symbol of meritocracy and the return to traditional intellectual values. Xi is two years older, and started college in 1975, when universities were still more focused on political indoctrination than education; he got his place as a “worker-peasant-soldier” student on the basis of political connections. Fairly or not, those experiences have formed how people interpret the two men: Li as a true child of the reform era, Xi with one foot still in the Mao era.

Writers have mined public records and private recollections to piece together pictures of their early years. Chun Han Wong’s new biography of Xi Party of One: The Rise of Xi Jinping and China’s Superpower Future, has a particularly valuable opening chapter on Xi’s early life, with lots of interesting details that are clearly sourced.

Xi was among nearly 2,700 students who enrolled at Tsinghua University’s Beijing campus in the fall of 1975 … as a worker-peasant-soldier student. He pursued a degree in organic chemistry, but university education at the time was more political than academic, marred by a lack of intellectual rigor and patchy teaching. One friend described Xi’s Tsinghua training as a degree in applied Marxism. Not that it mattered to Xi, who told another friend that he had no plans to work in the chemical industry. Xi, the friend recalled, “wanted to enter politics.”

While many of his peers indulged in romance, alcohol, and movies, Xi focused on politics, overseeing propaganda work as a member of his class’s party committee. Friends recalled a budding politician who showed savviness beyond his years.

More about what university life in China was like at that time, and what it exactly it meant to be a “worker-peasant-soldier” student comes from Jaime FlorCruz’s memoir The Class of ’77: How My Classmates Changed China. FlorCruz, a Filipino who later became an eminent foreign correspondent in Beijing, enrolled as a foreign student at Peking University in 1977, overlapping with both the last cohort of worker-peasant-soldier students and the new cohort of students who had passed the entrance examination. But his first encounter with Chinese university life came in 1971, when he visited as part of a unofficial delegation from the Philippines.

The makeup of the student body was curious as well. None of them had to take an entrance test to gain admission—a surprising development given that China was the historic originator of the concept of qualifying public service examinations. Many of the students we met had spent two to three years working in farms and factories; most of them, they said, got into Beida on the recommendation of the farmers and laborers they had worked with. Other students had previously served in the army and were similarly recommended.

The prerequisites for admission were simple: good health, work experience, and high “political consciousness.” Academic prowess was much less important than a student’s commitment to the ideals of the Chinese revolution and to the belief that working with one’s hands was better than book learning. As part of what Beida officials called the concept of “open-door schooling,” students were expected to extend their education beyond the classroom and to engage in street cleaning, farming, and assisting factory laborers with compiling “revolutionary histories” of their workplaces. These would help develop their moral, physical, ideological and intellectual character, we were told.

The guiding principle for all the subjects was a rigid Maoist perspective, including the doctrines of “combining theory with practice,” of “learning by doing,” and of “being socially relevant.” Students said that high grades were unimportant. Academic performance was rated as excellent, good, or fair but no one failed. Each class automatically moved from one level to another every year. Individual achievement was downplayed. Assignments were completed collectively, including the writing of essays and even sitting for examinations. In another break with tradition, where it once used to take four or six years to complete a degree like physics, the requirement had been reduced to two or three years.

The deficiencies of this system were pretty obvious, and Deng Xiaoping had already tried to overhaul university education in 1974, but was thwarted by conservative opposition. After the death of Mao in 1976, though, things changed quickly:

In 1977, Deng Xiaoping had not yet re-emerged as paramount leader, but he was already a force behind the scenes, and he and the other reformers knew that the existing worker-peasant-soldier student body of China’s universities would not be able to deliver his “Four Modernizations”—in agriculture, industry, science and technology, and defense. So, it was decided to overhaul the education system. One of the first results was the Class of ’77.

This class, the first step towards normalcy after the Cultural Revolution, was selected from a huge number of applicants of the “lost generation,” capable students whose studies had been cut short or denied after 1966. The average level of knowledge was much higher than those of the Worker-Peasant-Soldier students, who did not have to pass competitive entrance exams to enroll. The selection process for the Class of ’77 was a dramatic throwback to an older China, the revival of competitive qualifying examinations for college admission. It provided an opportunity for those who had been shut out of college for political reasons.

According to the memoirs of former vice-premier Li Lanqing, the demand for the college entrance examination was so high that the government ran out of paper on which to print the exams; the problem was solved by using paper that had been allocated for printing Mao’s Selected Works. FlorCruz’s account makes it clear how the return to exam-based meritocracy was very much a form of “class struggle” in reverse, an explicit decision to valorize the groups that had been targets during the Cultural Revolution and downgrade those (the workers, peasants, soldiers) who had been valorized.

Though separated by only two years in chronological age, Xi and Li ended up being situated on opposite sides of this historic divide in education. That must have had profound effects on their life experience and personality, though inevitably these we must speculate about most of these. In 2011, Chris Buckley interviewed many of Li Keqiang’s classmates from Peking University; the resulting piece gives a good flavor of the time, and why people expected Li to be relatively liberal. Li’s liberalism, if such it was, ended up being expressed more in terms of affect and attitude than in substance. Perhaps that’s because in the end what Xi and Li had in common outweighed those differences: both had political drive and ambition from an early age, and spent their adult lives pursuing ever-higher office in the same political system.

The fiscal consequences of a unitary state

The reason fiscal policy is interesting is that it is the concrete expression of a country’s political priorities: how governments spend money tells you how they work and what their priorities are. By the same token, it is impossible to really interpret fiscal policy without some understanding of the political structure in which the government operates. There are a lot of major differences in political structure–to put it mildly–between the country I grew up in, the US, and the country I have spent my professional life in, China. One of the ones whose importance took me a while to figure out is that China is a unitary state while the US is a federal state.

This issue springs to mind every time I read assertions like this about China: “The ratio of central government debt or sovereign debt to GDP is a mere 21 percent, the lowest among the world’s major economies.” (I’m quoting from the most recent example to have arrived in my inbox, but this argument is so widespread that I don’t need to pick on anyone in particular.) It is indeed true that, if you look at statistics on government debt in China, the majority of it is assigned to local governments rather than central governments (see chart). Many people therefore contend that while local governments have strained balance sheets and limited capacity to borrow further, the central government does not.

Such a distinction would make sense if China were a federal state: if the central and local governments were independent entities with clearly defined constitutional and legal roles and separate finances. But China is not a federal state, and local governments are not separate from the central government. There is only one government throughout China; local governments are merely the authorized agents of this state. There is no constitutional or legal support for the idea that China’s local governments have any independent fiscal power and could ever be considered as having balance sheets that are separate from the central government.

It’s true that China’s government is often deliberately obscure about its true organization and structure. But some things are out in the open. Let’s turn to the Constitution of the People’s Republic of China:

Article 105. Local people’s governments at various levels are the executive bodies of local organs of State power at various levels and are the local organs of State administration at the various levels.

Article 110. Local people’s governments at various levels throughout the country are all organs of State administration under the unified leadership of the State Council and are all subordinate to the State Council.

That’s pretty clear. There is only one government in China, and the State Council, meaning essentially the executive, controls that government. As a matter of constitutional theory, local governments have power and authority only because the State Council gives it to them. The fiscal implications of the unitary state are also clearly spelled out in the Law on the Administration of Tax Collection:

Article 5. The competent department for taxation under the State Council shall be in charge of the administration of tax collection throughout the country. The national tax bureaus and the local tax bureaus in various places shall administer tax collection respectively within the limits set by the State Council. 

The local people’s governments at various levels shall strengthen their leadership over or coordination of the administration of tax collection within their respective administrative regions, and support the tax authorities in performing out their duties in accordance with law, calculating the amounts of taxes to be paid according to the statutory tax rates and collecting taxes in accordance with law. 

This is also quite clear. The authority to raise tax revenue lies solely with the central government. Again as a matter of constitutional theory, local governments’ job is to help implement the tax policies decided by the central government. They do not have any authority to raise taxes on their own, and have no independent sources of revenue.

If you look at local government budgets in China, there are two sources of funds: revenue “at the local government level,” historically 55-60% of total revenue, and transfers from the central government, historically 40-45% of the total. In reality, though, these are the same thing: money from the central government. The central government allows local governments to retain a share of the taxes that are collected at the local level. The remainder that is handed over to the central government, and the taxes collected at the central level, are then redistributed back to local governments as transfers. Ultimately all tax revenue is controlled by the central government, which decides how much money local governments get.

What’s surprising is that, in a unitary state, there could even be such a thing as local government debt. And indeed before 2010 there was not. The local government bonds that have been sold since then are a curious thing: the central government approves their issuance, so the local governments do not have any independent borrowing authority. And the central government controls how much revenue local governments have, so whether local governments can repay the debt still ultimately depends on the central government. This is a weird arrangement. The central government could just issue the same amount of money in treasury bonds and redistribute it to local governments. But for internal political reasons that I honestly struggle to understand, it is considered desirable that some of this debt be “in the name” of local governments. Even though local governments do not have any authority to raise revenues to repay the debt!

Because of this unitary structure, it makes no sense to split either the income statement or the balance sheet of China’s government between central and local entities. There is only one state in China and its finances are unified. I should point out that an excellent recent quantitative overview of China’s government balance sheet by the IMF, “Fiscal Policy and the Government Balance Sheet in China,” does not fall victim to the fallacy I criticize; the authors follow best practices by presenting their assessment on a “general government” basis, i.e. the combination of central and local governments. That’s the right way!

What all this means is that you cannot wave away the debts of local governments by saying they are local, and it’s only central government debt that matters. The central and local governments are part of a single unitary state, and the central government is in charge of figuring out how to repay all of its debt. This is precisely why it has been such a disaster for the central government to allow local governments to engage in all that uncontrolled off-balance-sheet borrowing. If China was a federal state, local fiscal incontinence wouldn’t matter too much ultimately. When local authorities borrowed beyond their means, they eventually wouldn’t pay it back, and it would just be an issue between them and their creditors without national implications. But because China is a unitary state, every time local authorities abused their power by creating unauthorized liabilities, they worsened the fiscal situation for the entire state.

Moral of the story: a unitary state needs to act like one, not pretend to be a federal state. A combination of centralized revenue-raising authority and decentralized liability-creating authority is the worst of both worlds, and the sooner China gets away from it the better.

P.S. My thanks to the excellent NPC Observer website for making it easy to track down the relevant laws.

China wants those low-end industries after all

The usual goal of industrial policy is to, by supporting or protecting a particular industry, allow it to more quickly achieve the economies of scale necessary to be competitive. China has plenty of experience with this type of industrial policy: witness how it has scaled up in the manufacturing of solar power, lithium batteries, and electric vehicles to a size that dominates global markets. But the official rhetoric on industrial policy is now turning to a different and less well-trodden path: pursuing economies of scope as well as scale. Or, to put it in less technical terms: China’s government wants to preserve and improve competitiveness in a wide range of different industries, not just specialize in the most profitable ones. It sounds like a simple change, but it’s a significant one for China’s trading partners.

As is usual in China today, the signal of this change in priorities has been delivered by the man at the top, Xi Jinping. At the May meeting of the Central Commission on Financial and Economic Affairs, one of many steering groups he chairs, Xi laid out his vision of a “modernized industrial system.” He explained that such a modernized system has three key characteristics: it is “complete” ( 完整, also translated as “comprehensive”), “advanced” (先进) and “secure” (安全). The most novel of these objectives is “completeness,” and Xi briefly explained what that objective means in practice: “We must keep promoting the transformation and upgrading of traditional industries, and not take them as ‘low-end industries’ to be simply eliminated.”

On its surface, this could sound like one of the invocations of the importance of blue-collar manufacturing jobs now common in other countries on both the populist right and left. In fact, this statement is an intervention in a specific Chinese policy debate that clearly indicates a reversal of the previous direction. China’s turn toward high-technology-focused industrial policy well predates Xi, and actually began in the prior administration of General Secretary Hu Jintao and Premier Wen Jiabao (see Barry Naughton’s excellent short history of industrial policy for more).

In the mid- to late 2000s, “upgrading the industrial structure” was a regular buzzword, and official support for “emerging” and “strategic” industries ramped up. At the same time, though, the government tried to restrict resources going to less-desirable industries, usually defined as those that are highly polluting, energy-intensive, or in excess capacity. These efforts reached a peak in 2008; here is some representative language in Wen’s government work report from that year:

It is essential to appropriately control the scale of fixed asset investment and improve the investment structure. We will maintain strict control over the availability of land, credit and market access, and pay particular attention to strengthening and standardizing supervision of new projects to ensure they meet all the conditions for launching. Haphazard investment and unneeded development projects in energy intensive and highly polluting industries and industries with excess production capacity will be resolutely stopped, and market access will be tightened and capital requirements will be increased for industries whose development is discouraged. Work on illegal projects will be resolutely stopped.

In this vision of industrial upgrading, there is both positive and negative discrimination: the government pursues policies that favor high-end industries and disfavor low-end industries. Such a vision is based on ideas of national specialization and integrated global trade. It’s influenced by the “flying geese” model originally articulated by a Japanese scholar and popular among development economists in the 1980s and 1990s. The idea is that, as nations advance up the technological ladder, they leave behind production of low-value or commoditized products, which then creates opportunities for lower-income countries to industrialize by making those goods. Nations at different income levels specialize in making different kinds of products, and by trading with each other everyone becomes better off.

Xi’s vision of “completeness” or “comprehensiveness” does away with this. Rather than allowing China’s low-end industries to shift to other, lower-income countries, and then importing those products, the idea is to maintain the ability to produce the full range of goods within China. Low-end industries are not abandoned but become targets for technological upgrading in order to preserve their competitiveness. As the Chinese economist Xu Zhaoyuan explained in an exegesis of Xi’s remarks:

We cannot allow traditional industries to transfer abroad too quickly. This requires continuous strengthening of policy support for the upgrading and transformation of traditional industries, improving product innovation and efficiency to enhance their competitiveness, while also continuously reducing the cost burden of the real economy, especially reducing various transaction costs. 

The background assumption is clearly no longer that nations can specialize to take advantage of an open global trading system, but rather that they need to minimize external dependencies and vulnerability to trade disruption. The Chinese economist Yu Yongding called it part of China’s response to the US decoupling campaign:

Re-emphasizing the importance of comprehensiveness is a reaction to the new geopolitical reality. While China cannot and should not produce everything – autarky is impossible for a modern economy – it should be able to quickly launch or increase production of critical goods, as needed.

China does indeed have a very broad range of manufacturing competence: according to Yu, “China ranked among the world’s top three exporters (by volume) in 2,400 of 4,000 categories of intermediate goods traded globally between 2017 and 2020.” More simply, there are very few goods that China does not make. I looked at China’s exports broken down by 4-digit HS code; out of 1,241 categories, there were zero exports in fewer than 50, a share that has remained largely constant over the past decade.

In a sense, then, achieving a “complete” industrial industrial system would just mean maintaining the status quo. On the other hand, as China is probably only a few years away from qualifying as a “high-income” country on the World Bank’s definition, one might expect that rising incomes would have at least some impact on China’s cost structures and competitiveness in making in different products.

As is often the case with these high-level slogans, it’s not totally clear what the practical implications of Xi’s policy shift are going to be. It would not be that unreasonable for Xi to say, “I don’t think we should have government policies that actively try to shut down particular industries, because those industries employ Chinese people and earn money and there’s just no good reason to get rid of them.” It would be somewhat less reasonable, certainly from the perspective of China’s trading partners, for Xi to say “Instead of just subsidizing the high-tech industries of the future, I think we should subsidize every single industry that China has so that China can have a comparative advantage in making everything.”

At the least, the rhetoric of “completeness” does not offer a lot of hope that other countries are going to be able to benefit from China’s growth by selling it stuff. The “flying geese” theory is now criticized, not totally unfairly in my view, for contributing to the hollowing-out of industry in the US and other high-income countries. But it did offer a basis for mutually beneficial trade with the developing world: as high-income countries lost competitive advantage in some industries, the low-income countries gained it, and could use those industries to raise their own incomes.

China these days is trying to knit together a coalition of other developing countries also opposed to US dominance of the global system. But its official economic theory does not offer much of a basis for what it likes to call “win-win” ties with other developing countries. China wants to keep producing itself all the stuff that poorer developing nations in Africa, Asia and elsewhere might want to sell it. China acknowledges a need to import necessary raw materials, and that’s about it. Is this maximum mercantilism really an attractive vision for an alternative global economic order?

The political position of the private sector

Are China’s private-sector businesspeople unhappy about living under a Communist government? That is the increasingly explicit contention of some commentators on China’s current economic troubles. The idea is that Xi Jinping has reversed the Communist Party’s recent historical accommodation with the private sector, leaving entrepreneurs fundamentally uncertain about their future prospects. If business owners do not believe they can earn a profit without risk of intervention or confiscation by the government, then they will not invest, and the economy will not grow. As Adam Tooze put it in a typically thoughtful overview of this school of thought, the key contention is that “the problems of China’s economy are political and though they center on Xi they go beyond him and concern the entire system.”

Bill Bishop’s Sinocism newsletter of July 19 has a useful summary of some of the Party’s recent ideological pronouncements that “may have caused some skepticism in the private sector.” Among the most explicit was a 2020 document (English translation here) that detailed measures to “continuously strengthen the Party’s leadership over the private economy” and “educate and guide private economy practitioners to…unswervingly listen to and follow the Party.” While the document also discusses the Party’s duty to support private businesses and respond to their concerns, it is fair to say that it does not envisage a hands-off relationship in which the private sector is allowed to go about its own affairs.

Xi’s politicization of the private sector’s role in Chinese society is often contrasted, implicitly or explicitly, with the high-level accommodation of the interests of the private sector that existed under previous leaders. In 2001, Jiang Zemin famously welcomed private entrepreneurs into the ranks of the Communist Party and pledged that the Party would respect and support their interests, under his slogan of the “Three Represents.”

This dramatic ideological shift has sometimes been interpreted by critics on the left, inside and outside China, as a “neoliberal turn” in which the state served as the handmaiden of private capitalists. In reality, Jiang’s concerns were not so different from Xi’s: his goal was also to ensure that the private business sector would not evolve into a political opposition (in general, Jiang’s role in setting the fundamental parameters of China’s post-1992 political economy is often underrated).

The historian Frank Dikötter, in his recent book China After Mao: The Rise of a Superpower, points out that while the Three Represents did open Party membership to entrepreneurs, it also began a push to extend Party cells into private businesses:

Although few people knew exactly what the formulation meant, the general idea was that the party should not dilute its own political power and must ensure it remained in the vanguard of every area of life. This included the country’s ‘advanced culture’ as well as the ‘fundamental interest of the majority of the people’. A third principle posited that the party should ‘represent the foremost production forces’.

Foreign experts gasped with admiration, as the Three Represents included a decision to end a ban on party membership for private business people. But in typical Orwellian doublespeak, the campaign was designed to extend the hand of the state, not retract it, most of all in the private sector. Since tens of thousands of state enterprises were becoming shareholding companies, shedding millions of jobs along the way, the party insisted on maintaining control. The Three Represents meant that party cells must be established even within private businesses, subjecting them to closer party supervision.

Some of Jiang Zemin’s comments from the time on the issue of the Party and the private sector are reproduced in Volume III of his Selected Works. In May 2000, he visited Nanjing, Suzhou and Shanghai–some of the historical centers of China’s private businesses–and held discussions about “Party building,” meaning the establishment of Party cells in private businesses. Here are a few of the key passages, which also highlight the need to ensure private companies support the Party line:

There are nearly 1.5 million private enterprises and more than 31 million individual industrial and commercial businesses (getihu) nationwide, employing more than 82 million people. In terms of either economic strength or the number of people, the weight is not light. … This has raised a new topic for us, which is how to strengthen the party’s leadership in these fields, and effectively unite and organize the masses in these fields around the party. …

It is necessary to promptly carry out the work of party building in non-public economic organizations. Carrying out party building work in non-public enterprises is a new field. In recent years, some places have actively explored and achieved some results. But in general, the development is very uneven, obviously lagging behind the requirements of the development of the situation. According to incomplete statistics, currently 83.3 percent of private enterprises in the country have no party members, and only 1.4 percent of the total number of enterprises have established party organizations. …

Today’s private business owners have developed under our Party’s reform policy and the call to get rich first, and many of them are laborers. The Party organization should actively do a good job of uniting, educating, and guiding them in accordance with policy, unite them around the Party organization, and make them support the establishment of Party organizations in enterprises, support the Party’s various policies, operate enterprises according to the law, care for and protect employees’ rights and interests, and contribute to the country and society.

Surveys by the All-China Federation of Industry and Commerce document that the share of private companies with a Party cell rose sharply after the initial launch of the Three Represents slogan in 2000. Xi has also emphasized Party-building in the private sector, and has presided over a lot of political messaging and actions designed to enforce the idea that private businesses have a duty to be loyal to the Party and support the Party’s policies. But this is not a new idea, and private businesses have had a couple of decades, if not more, to get used to it.

To me, the historical evidence suggests Xi’s ideology probably does not differ a lot from his predecessors in terms of the private sector’s political position in Chinese society. And therefore I’m not sure that such ideological messaging is the real problem affecting private business in China today. What I do think is different under Xi, and where he has created instability and uncertainty, is his articulation of the goals that China’s political system is trying to achieve.

As Xi has repeatedly said, sometimes with evident frustration for those who still have not gotten the message, what he is trying to do is reorient China’s political system away from the pursuit of economic growth at all costs. From his perspective, that pursuit created a lot of political problems that need to be corrected: corruption, waste, loss of Party discipline.

But one of the political benefits of the orientation toward economic growth is that it offers a fundamental assurance that the interests of the Party and the interests of private businesses are aligned. If growth is the goal, then ultimately the Party wants companies’ revenues and profits to go up, and that is the same thing the companies want. If growth is not the goal, then the Party’s interests and the interests of private businesses can diverge. And that prospect could reasonably trouble businesses who understand their political position.

Stimulus is never just temporary

As China’s data continue to disappoint, there is a persistent theme in much of the outside commentary on its economic woes: that China is for some reason failing to take the “obvious” step of sending stimulus checks to households. The implicit argument is that the US handed out massive subsidies directly to households, got a great post-pandemic recovery and everything turned out fine. China did not deliver subsidies to households, and that’s why everything is very much not fine.

Why is China, still, not taking this course in spite of the positive example of the US? Of course, an obvious answer is that the people in charge don’t think the US example was that positive, and anyway aren’t particularly prone to think of the US as a model to emulate. The merits of the pandemic fiscal-policy response are still pretty contested in the US. Plenty of people think of the stimulus as a fiscally irresponsible gamble that ultimately had pretty disruptive macroeconomic effects, because of the huge interest-rate increases that were required to bring inflation under control; my perception is that many people in China share these views. Still, the case for stimulus is probably getting stronger rather than weaker at the moment as China falls further away from potential growth and full employment.

My suspicion is that part of Chinese policymakers’ reluctance to use direct transfers to households as a short-term stimulus stems from a fear of setting a fiscally destabilizing precedent. If debt-financed transfers failed to generate a sustainable recovery, the money would be wasted. But if transfers succeeded in generating a good burst of growth, that could have even bigger longer-term effects. It would mean that, the next time China falls short of potential growth and full employment, the political pressure to roll out household transfers again would be overwhelming. What started as a one-off policy response could become entrenched as the expected response to any growth slowdown, and would add to government deficits and debt over many years rather than just one.

Why should this hypothetical possibility be a serious concern for Chinese policymakers? Because it is exactly what happened after the 2008 financial crisis. An unprecedented global shock led to an unprecedented policy response, as the central government encouraged local authorities to use off-balance-sheet borrowing to fund a wave of public works projects. If that had been a one-off measure, it would have been a powerful example of effective and unorthodox policymaking. Instead, the infrastructure stimulus institutionalized fiscal irresponsibility on a massive scale: a decade and a half on, the off-balance-sheet local borrowing is even bigger relative to the economy than it was in 2008, according to IMF estimates. It would be hard to find a better example of Milton Friedman’s quip that “nothing is so permanent as a temporary government program.”

China’s political system therefore does not have a good track record of being able to take away the punch bowl in good economic times in order to be able to share out more punch in the bad times. The dubious legacy of the 2008 stimulus means that China now needs fiscal consolidation to get long-term debt dynamics under control–at exactly the moment that it once again faces a shortage of aggregate demand.

Striking the right balance between the structural and cyclical issues is indeed quite difficult. Maybe the right answer is in fact that the cycle needs more attention at the moment, because a failure to address the loss of growth momentum would allow hysteresis to set in and create even more long-term costs for the economy. But it is perhaps understandable that the people inside China’s system are reluctant to experiment with new forms of fiscal stimulus before they have gotten the old ones under control.

The persistence of markets under Mao

What accounts for the extraordinary rise of China’s private sector after the economic reforms that followed Mao’s death? The 1980s were a pivotal decade for China in many ways, as the rapid growth of the private sector transformed the structure of a still officially socialist economy. In 1987, Deng Xiaoping famously said that the explosion of private-sector activity in the countryside in particular came as a surprise to him:

In the rural reform our greatest success — and it is one we had by no means anticipated — has been the emergence of a large number of enterprises run by villages and townships. They were like a new force that just came into being spontaneously. …If the Central Committee made any contribution in this respect, it was only by laying down the correct policy of invigorating the domestic economy. The fact that this policy has had such a favourable result shows that we made a good decision. But this result was not anything that I or any of the other comrades had foreseen; it just came out of the blue.

Of course, the township and village enterprises–which is to say, private companies avant la lettre–did not actually come out of nowhere. They drew on China’s long traditions of commercial enterprise, and people’s experience with living and operating in a market economy before it was suppressed in the 1950s. In an interesting new paper, “Markets under Mao: Measuring Underground Activity in the Early PRC” (the link is currently open-access), Adam Frost and Zeren Li offer quantitative evidence to suggest that hidden market activities continued at scale even through the height of the Maoist period:

There was already substantial market-based activity prior to the launch of economic reforms. Even after the “socialist transformation” of the Chinese economy was ostensibly complete, Chinese citizens continued participating in “underground market activity,” i.e. private acts of exchange that occurred outside of systems of planned allocation and distribution and which were intentionally concealed from the state. A broad host of actors, ranging from rural people who “abandoned farming to take up commerce” to merchants who specialized in the illicit wholesale trade of ration certificates, devised novel strategies to evade state control and engaged in consensual private transactions. While these individuals often filled critical voids in the economy, they were collectively maligned as “speculators and profiteers” and, for three decades, were the recurring targets of mass campaigns. Yet, even at the height of the Cultural Revolution when anti-capitalist sentiments reached their zenith, “speculation and profiteering” were never wholly suppressed.

The authors use local administrative documents recovered from flea markets to compile data on 2,690 cases of “speculation and profiteering” that authorities prosecuted in two areas, the rural county of Chun’an in Zhejiang and the city of Zhenjiang in Jiangsu. These records often list what items the “speculators” were accused of selling, and at a what price. The value of the transactions was usually pretty substantial:

The mean case value (i.e. the estimated total value of activity described in each case) is about 334 yuan for Chun’an and 362 yuan for Zhenjiang. To put these figures into perspective, in 1955 the national average income was 102 yuan for an urban worker and 94 yuan for a rural farmer, and income levels remained stagnant for most of the 1960s and 1970s. In other words, the mean case involved activity that represented three years’ worth of consumption for the mean worker. Given that prosecuted individuals probably succeeded in concealing some portion of their gains, this figure is likely only a fraction of the true quantities of goods, cash, and ration certificates involved in each case.

The authors use various assumptions to estimate the total size of underground market activity from these figures. The results depend so much on assumptions that the exact figures are not particularly meaningful, but the range of estimates is consistent with contemporary estimates of the “shadow economy” of illegal transactions in most countries–perhaps suggesting that Maoist China was more economically normal than its ideology would indicate. This finding is also interesting:

We observe that the average spread between the purchase and resale price of items in underground market transactions was relatively low and remained so throughout the entire period of observation. There was, on average, no more than a 19% mark-up on items that were bought and resold in underground markets. These figures suggest that the maximum perceived risk of capture was low, even during the height of the Cultural Revolution.

The low black-market premium also suggests these kind of underground transactions were widespread enough that the scarcity value was not extreme, and that underground traders faced enough competition that they could not charge exorbitant prices. The repeated campaigns against “speculation and profiteering” that generated these administrative documents therefore do not seem to have been particularly successful. When the formal prohibitions on these private transactions were lifted in the post-1978 reforms, many Chinese people had plenty of experience with trading and business that could be quickly put to use.

Frost and Li’s account lines up with my own thinking about the reasons for the early success of China’s economic reforms–although when I pondered this question before, I focused more on the fact that China did not actually spend that much a time as a full-fledged socialist economy (see my previous post, “How long was China Communist?“). The time from the forced nationalization of private firms in the mid-1950s to the re-legalization of urban and rural private sectors in the early 1980s was barely three decades. By contrast, socialist prohibitions on private enterprise in the Soviet Union lasted two full generations, long enough to wipe out any previously existing base of skills and knowledge formed in the private commercial economy (which was not that developed in tsarist Russia anyway).

These two explanations seem fully complementary to me: China’s socialist prohibitions on private transactions were neither complete enough to truly stamp out market-based activities, nor did they last long enough to for the population of people with experience running businesses in a market economy to die off. Once the state began to tolerate markets again, the hidden traditions of private enterprise could come out into the open.

Peak globalization and China’s EV exports

The rise of electric vehicles is one of the most interesting and consequential changes in the world’s industrial structure to come along in some time. Among other things, it has enabled the Chinese government to fulfill its long-held dream of becoming a globally competitive producer of passenger cars; in a very short period of time, China has become a major exporter of electric vehicles. The International Energy Agency has some useful summary statistics in its Global EV Outlook:

China is a leading exporter of electric cars, representing over 35% of electric car exports, as well as of batteries. Europe is China’s largest trade partner for both electric cars and their batteries. Indeed, over the past year the share of electric cars sold in the European market coming from China increased from about 11% in 2021 to about 16% in 2022.

Over the past five years, the share of global electric car exports coming from China has increased more than eightfold, with China becoming the largest exporter in 2021 and the gap further widening in 2022. The share of electric car exports from the United States peaked in 2019 and has since fallen below the levels exported from China, Korea and Europe.

This is an undeniable success for China’s strategy of building up a complete domestic supply chain for the batteries and other components going into electric vehicles. But it’s a success that has also depended on partnerships with multinational companies. According to EV Volumes, China exported about 580,000 electric vehicles in 2022, of which 407,000, or around 70%, were “Western brands.” (Just to give an idea of the speed of growth, exports in the first half of 2023 have already topped 500,000 units,)

By far the most important of those Western brands is Tesla, which according to the IEA accounted for about 40% of China’s EV exports in 2022. Another 20% of China’s EV exports were from European companies; this should include the Renault-Nissan group and BMW. (The remaining 10% are probably “Western brands” that are Chinese-owned: SAIC owns the British MG brand and makes MG-branded EVs in China, while Geely controls Volvo and Polestar, whose EVs are made in China for export).

The success of China’s EV exports is therefore inseparable from the decisions of multinational companies to make China their base for global EV exports (and of other countries’ willingness to allow a level of Chinese investment in their auto industries that China would not have allowed for foreign investment in its own auto industry).

Those decisions go back some years. BMW’s joint venture in China started making EVs as far back as 2013, started producing the iX3 in 2020 and opened another $2.2 billion EV plant in 2022. The Renault-Nissan group announced an EV joint venture with Dongfeng in 2017; it started out making models for the domestic market, but is also now making the Dacia Spring for export to Europe.

Tesla’s major investment in its Shanghai factory came a bit later, only after China’s decision to remove the requirement that foreign automakers operate through joint ventures. This liberalization took effect in 2018 for EVs and in 2022 for other vehicles. In addition to its direct effects on exports, Tesla’s entry into China is also generally credited with injecting new dynamism into the domestic market:

Despite all that government support, sales of EVs remained weak until 2019, when China let Tesla open a wholly owned factory in Shanghai. “It took this catalyst…to boost interest and increase the level of competitiveness of the local Chinese makers,” said Tu Le, managing director of Sino Auto Insights, a research service specializing in the Chinese auto industry.

Electric vehicles were less than 5% of domestic vehicle sales until 2020, really took off in 2021, and have surged since then to around 30% of domestic sales. According to another analyst:

Tesla’s brand appeal helped nudge more consumers to switch from gas-powered cars. A supply chain built around Tesla now feeds a wave of improving homegrown EV makers. “If you’re China: thank you Tesla for waking up the part of the market which was sleeping, which was retail consumers,” said Bill Russo, founder and CEO of Automobility, a Shanghai-based strategy and investment advisory firm.

The current success of China’s EV industry therefore has to be seen as a success of globalization–the flow of international capital seeking out the most efficient location–not just for domestically focused industrial policy. It’s the interaction between those two factors that has given China’s EV exports their rather unusual composition.

But in 2023, after the trade war, the Ukraine war and the collapse of US-China relations, the international structure of China’s EV exports also looks like the peak of a particular form of globalization that will not be reached again anytime soon. In 2013 or 2017 it was definitely not controversial for a Western multinational to choose China as the global export base for a major new product; in 2023 it certainly would be. In the current political climate it is very hard to imagine Western multinationals making such decisions again without hesitation.

The global rise of China’s EV industry looks like it is just getting started. But the model that kick-started that rise may not be available for repeat use.

Some cadres cannot keep up

Some of Xi Jinping’s most revealing comments about economic policy have come when he is ostensibly not talking about the economy at all. Official media have recently published a speech he gave on March 1, 2022 at the Central Party School, in which he mainly talks about ethics, ideals, responsibilities–the heavy burden that young Communist Party cadres must bear in their careers.

But it also contains some fairly frank remarks about the conduct of local government officials. Xi has made it his mission to reorient China’s political system away from the decentralized pursuit of growth-at-all-costs, and he is frustrated that not everyone is on board:

Most cadres can actively adapt to the new development requirements, but some cadres cannot keep up. Some think that development is about launching projects, doing investments, and expanding scale, and even still regard highly polluting and energy-consuming projects as an important means of promoting economic growth. Some over-borrow to build and blindly expand businesses. Some methods are simple and crude: the “one size fits all” campaign-style reduction in carbon emissions led to large-scale power shortages and seriously affected enterprise production and people’s livelihood. And so on.

The criticism of local-government debts and wasteful investments, long tolerated and even encouraged by the central government, is notable. Later on in the speech he draws on his own experiences in local government to make a broader point:

When I was working in Ningde [in 1988-89], the central government carried out rectification in response to intensifying inflation and the serious problem of duplicate construction. Ningde’s economy was affected as a result, and some cadres didn’t understand and complained. I said that this part of eastern Fujian must comply with the overall design for the whole province and the whole country; if the current macroeconomic adjustment work requires sacrificing some local interests, this should be willingly accepted.

Today, some cadres still have a parochial mentality. When something happens, they think first of departmental interests, local interests, and small-group interests. They play games with the Party Center’s decisions, selectively implementing them, or using fraud to hide their lack of compliance. ….Leading cadres must think about problems and do things from the perspective of the overall situation and strategy. All work must be based on the implementation of the Party Center’s decisions, and cannot damage the interests of the whole for the sake of local interests, or damage fundamental and long-term interests for the sake of temporary interests.

These comments reinforced my feeling that Xi’s economic strategy is ultimately political. He is not mainly opposed to the decentralized local pursuit of growth because he thinks it is a sub-optimal way to run the economy, or because it contributes to imbalances and inefficiency–the kind of critiques that economists make. Rather, he doesn’t like it because it has undermined Communist Party discipline and increased corruption. Growth-at-all-costs turns out to have had a high political cost, in the context of China’s top-down Leninist system.

As Joseph Fewsmith’s excellent book Rethinking Chinese Politics argues, this problem was evident from the very beginning of the reform era, and indeed was inevitable given the nature of reform:

There are tensions built into Leninism that reform unleashes. In particular, the role of cadres changes. No longer the object of mass political campaigns to control their behavior or able to use political campaigns to control the behavior of others, local cadres pursue economic development and often self-enrichment. Doing so often requires developing close relations with other cadres and developing ties with economic actors in society. Local networks and corruption are an inevitable consequence of reform. In short, a degree of party dysfunctionality is a part and parcel of reform. Local cadres become less responsive to higher-level commands and conflict with society is a by-product of politically directed economic reform. That reform erodes control and discipline in Leninist systems is wholly predictable. The impact of reform on Leninism was visible from the start.

Xi’s centralizing agenda is perhaps best understood, Fewsmith argues, as an attempt to “reinvigorate” Leninism, pushing back against the loss of Party discipline rather than accepting its inevitable decline into a welter of competing interest groups.